Sunday, June 5, 2022
HomeMacroeconomicsnationalisation or regulation, and Sunak's spring statement

nationalisation or regulation, and Sunak’s spring statement


 

A
comparison of the extent of energy price increases for consumers in
the UK and France has attracted a lot of attention. The French
government, in a presidential election year, has been quick to limit
the extent
of any increase for the
consumer resulting from massive increases in wholesale prices
following the recovery from the pandemic and, more recently, Putin’s
invasion of Ukraine. In contrast in the UK the
regulator, Ofgem, has set a very large increase in its price
cap, which will be painful for all UK consumers from this Spring. (On
the origins of the price cap see Giles Wilkes here.)

This
in turn has reopened the debate between two different styles of
relationship between the government and parts of the energy industry:
nationalisation (EDF is largely owned by the French government) or
regulation of privately owned companies (as in the UK). Many
consumers will naturally see the ability of the government to
directly limit energy prices as an advantage of the nationalisation
model. In addition much has been made of the large increase in profits of many energy companies.

Any
discussion on this issue can easily get bogged down in details. It is
important to distinguish between energy
supply
(e.g. BP and Shell) and distribution (in the UK, dominated
by the Big
6
).

The
profits of the former are bound to rise when prices rise by far more
than the cost of extracting energy. In the UK Ofgem regulates energy
distribution, and when energy market prices rise this increases the
costs these companies have to pay. This is the reason for the rise in
Ofgem’s price cap, although that seems to be consistent with a recent
large
increase in profits

of the Big 6.

I
want to abstract from this detail by thinking about a single
(‘vertically integrated’) energy company that both supplies and
distributes. The reason is that I want to focus on the distinction between
prices and profits (or who benefits from higher prices). It is
possible for the government to allow higher prices, but to tax the
profits those higher prices bring to companies, and use these
‘windfall taxes’ to transfer money to consumers or for some other
socially useful purpose. I want to argue here that this is exactly
what should be happening right now.

Prices
send out signals to both consumers and firms. Higher prices imply a
commodity has seen a reduction in supply or a rise in demand, which
encourages consumers to economise on using the commodity where they
can. Equally the higher profits that tend to come with higher prices
encourage firms to invest more to produce more of the commodity. The
price signal is doing a useful job on both accounts.

However
with energy, which at the margin is produced by burning carbon, it is
also vital that we think about climate change, which is proceeding
largely unchecked in an alarming
way
. Global warming is sometimes described by economists as the
world’s biggest externality, by which they mean that the need to
reduce climate change by consuming less carbon is not reflected in prices.

From
the point of view of reducing carbon usage the higher prices for gas
and electricity are beneficial. It is good to encourage less use of
energy because that helps reduce climate change. By widening the gap
between carbon based energy production and renewables, higher prices
also encourage green energy supply. However higher energy prices also
encourage additional extraction of oil and gas, and national governments typically don’t stop energy firms doing this (some may
indeed encourage it).

It
is in this context that we need to consider a recent proposal
from the European Commission. They suggest member countries tax the
profits energy companies made from recent energy price spikes and invest
the revenue in renewable energy and energy-saving renovations. In
doing this, the proposal suggests, EU governments would not be
falling foul of EU rules.

The
important point is that ‘excess’ profits are taxed, rather than
what the money is spent on. Tax increases are not normally directly
linked to how that money is spent (they are not hypothecated).
In the UK more money is desperately needed by the poorest to help pay
higher food and energy bills, and that is best provided by raising
levels of Universal Credit. Whether the government does that from
general taxation, some other means or from a windfall tax is
incidental beyond media announcements.

The
purpose of a windfall tax on energy companies is to ensure that the
high profits made by these firms do not end up as paying for
investment in non-green energy production, or as dividends or capital
gains (from share buy-backs)
to owners of the shares of those firms, but are directed to a more
socially useful end. 

What
are the arguments against taxing the profits generated by high market
prices? Let’s look at an FT editorial
entitled “Windfall taxes on energy companies are a bad idea”.
Among many paragraphs, the only substantive argument appears to be
this:

 

“Stability
is key to promoting both investment and spending — both of which
drive economic growth. Predictable and constant regulations are
identifiers of a society governed by the rule of law.”

Stability,
the ultimate last resort of the conservative, is a non-argument in
this case, as I would be quite happy to enshrine in the rule of law a
tax schedule for these companies that taxes very high profits at a
high marginal rate. Redirecting high profits to either green
investment or higher benefits to the poor would also drive economic
growth, with rather more drive than if the profits end up with
shareholders. The editorial has all the hallmarks of some poor junior
scribe being told to write something about why windfall taxes are a
bad idea, and having to scrape the barrel to find any decent
argument. I’m glad to see that Chris Giles, senior FT economics
editor, has recently written in favour of windfall taxes on energy
companies in the FT here. (More bogus arguments are debunked by Michael Jacobs here.)

One
argument against nationalisation is that politicians come under huge
pressure to keep prices low, as consumers (who are also voters) see
the immediate benefit of lower prices, while the higher taxes, lower
spending or whatever that is the counterpart of subsidizing energy is
more opaque. A regulator is not under similar electoral pressure, and
can ensure prices send appropriate signals. However such an argument
against nationalisation can only be made if the government is
prepared to implement windfall taxes on energy companies when their
profits are very high, and that is something the UK government has
not so far been prepared to do.

This
argument is also central to the Chancellor’s Spring Statement
tomorrow. The Resolution Foundation sets out some of his options
here.
A cut in fuel duty, though widely expected, just subsidises CO2
emissions at a significant cost to the public. Hardly surprising from successive Conservative Chancellors who keep promising to put up fuel duty and keep failing to do so, making nonsense of claims this is a green government. On other measures, Sunak should focus on a large uprating in universal benefit which provides
most help to those who need it, as the Resolution Foundation shows.

But
there are few votes for him in helping the poor, so that outcome
seems less likely to happen.

Postscript (24/03/22): Sunak’s Spring Statement shows that Sunak has not given up hope of soon replacing Johnson as Prime Minister. He announced a set of measures that did little to tackle the cost of living crisis most people face, did little to help the economy, but was designed to appeal to a majority of Conservative MPs that Sunak needs to become Prime Minister. So what does his package tell us about the average Tory MP?

First, their ideology has not progressed much from Thatcherism. They want tax cuts and a smaller state, and Sunak used the cost of living crisis to give them both. With government spending plans already fixed in nominal terms, higher inflation produced a squeeze on spending but higher taxes, and Sunak used that additional revenue to produce some modest tax cuts. This ideology is completely unsuited to the times, as both Johnson and Sunak had acknowledged by raising health spending and taxes by far more in the Autumn, but it remains what Conservative MPs are comfortable with. Neoliberalism may be dying, but it lives on in the minds of many Conservative MPs. 

Second, most Conservative MPs still regard tackling climate change as ‘green crap’ that they have to make a token of supporting but will not let get in the way of their ideology or electoral fortunes. So we had some VAT relief for insulation and heat pumps (the token), but there was no windfall tax on energy companies (see above) but instead a cut in fuel duty to encourage more car use. The words net zero did not appear in his speech, perhaps because it didn’t occur to Sunak that it should, but more likely because he wants to have those MPs that want to scrap the net zero commitment on board.

Third, Conservative MPs are landlords rather than tenants, so he promised to cut income tax rates before the election while at the same time putting up national insurance contributions. This is almost giving with one hand while taking with the other, except that national insurance contributions are not paid by anyone who gets their income from sources other than working, like landlords or that favorite Tory voting group, pensioners. A sure way of appealing to Conservative MPs is to appeal to their pockets. Overall, if we combine this statement with decisions taken last Autumn, the Chancellor is not helping working people deal with the cost of living crisis, but making that crisis much worse, as this OBR chart shows. The average wage is expected to fall by 1% before tax compared to last year, but by 3% after tax by next year as Sunak’s tax rises take hold. 

The UK’s cost of living crisis is in large part the Chancellor’s choice as he puts deficit targets above the needs of working people.  

Fourth and worst of all, your typical Conservative MP does not care one jot about the poor or disabled, and indeed is quite happy to stigmatize those on benefits if that brings electoral advantage. Whereas the Conservative party pretends to be green, it doesn’t even pretend to care about poverty. As I note above, the single most effective measure to help those who need it most to weather the cost of living crisis – to keep food on their plates and houses warm – was an increase in universal credit, but that was not part of Sunak’s plan. Indeed the whole budget was designed to help middle earners at the expense of the poor, whose in and out of work benefits will be uprated by past inflation while current inflation is more than double this. The reason for this indifference has very little to do with Sunak’s personal wealth, and rather more to do with who votes Conservative. The best way to appeal to a Conservative MP is to appeal to those likely to vote for them.

So we got a Spring Statement that Conservative MPs can cheer, but will allow an estimated 1.3 million in the UK to fall into absolute poverty. We got a Spring Statement that, combined with earlier decisions, will make the cost of living crisis far worse for the average worker, but is good for landlords, pensioners and those with unearned income. A Spring Statement that ignores the opportunity to divert record energy company profits into helping the poor and greening the economy. A Spring Statement that reflects one man’s desire for power, and how unrepresentative and out of touch with working people most Conservative MPs are.  

     



RELATED ARTICLES

LEAVE A REPLY

Please enter your comment!
Please enter your name here

- Advertisment -
Google search engine

Most Popular

Recent Comments