Tuesday, July 19, 2022
HomeMacroeconomicsmyths of left and right about inflation and trade unions

myths of left and right about inflation and trade unions


 

With a global energy
price hike generating high inflation in most countries, and central
banks reacting by raising interest rates, comparisons with the 1970s
are in fashion. The 1970s have for a long time been seen by the
political right in the UK and US as the chaos before the calm, where
the calm is the advent of neoliberalism. For much the same reasons, a
common refrain on the left is that the 1970s were a lot better than
what came later in many ways. A good example of the latter is a
recent article
by Adam Tooze in Foreign Policy. While taking the kind of holistic
view he does there has its merits, it also frames the debate as an
answer to the question ‘1970s: good or bad?’, while reality is
more complex than that. In this post I just want to focus on just two
issues: inflation and trade unions.

Tooze says that successfully controlling inflation (through independent central banks) was a victory for conservative politics. Historically inflation produces winners (borrowers) and losers (savers), and so controlling inflation was a victory for savers. In addition high inflation goes with unpredictable volatility. Inflation started at 5% in 1970, rose to over 25% in the mid-seventies, then fell to below 10% only to rise again in the early 1980s. So those who prefer stability, like most business owners, will also prefer low and stable inflation. But the constituency that enjoyed the high and variable inflation of the 1970s is both small and lacks political representation. 

The high
and variable inflation of the 1970s was generally unpopular, and as a
result no political party campaigned for it, just as no political groups today are arguing that the current increase in inflation should continue. I think it would be fairer to say that successfully controlling inflation is generally popular, rather than characterise it as a victory for conservative forces. There are many reasons
why high and variable inflation is unpopular. While economists often
focus on the costs of unwarranted relative price dispersion, what was
far worse in the 1970s was heightened social disruption. 
Days lost in strikes reached a post-war peak in the 1970s and early 1980s.
Strikes are costly because of lost pay and production, but also because
of the social dislocation they can cause. 

The political right likes
to slide from this observation to suggest that strikes are always the
fault of workers, or even worse ‘trade union barons’. Their
predictability on this makes their
claim
to be ‘the party of the working class’ risible.

Many on the left do
the opposite. Strikes, after all, appear to be the archetypal battle
between workers and capital. Unfortunately this overlooks one key
point, which is that firms also set prices. As a result, when
inflation is widespread strikes are not a battle between wages and
profits for their share of any surplus, because employers can often
recoup their share of the surplus by raising their prices. The
reality is that strikes represent the breakdown of negotiations
between two sides, where either workers, employers, both or none can
be to blame. Such breakdowns tend to be bad for both the employers
and employees involved, and often for many who use the products or
services they create. 
High and volatile inflation goes together with a high number of days lost through strikes for obvious reasons. 

The unfortunate
reality that is often missed on the left, but which is understood by
most macroeconomists, is that a large increase in global energy
prices have to lead at some point to a corresponding reduction in
real wages (compared to what they otherwise would have been), for
reasons I discussed here.
Governments can and should act to cushion that effect for those on
low incomes (and more widely if higher commodity prices don’t
redistribute from consumers to those working to produce commodities
but instead redistribute
to the profits of commodity producing multinationals
),
but unless higher energy prices are known to be temporary there is no
reason to permanently cushion that impact for all workers, and good
reasons
why they shouldn’t. 

In these
circumstances, suggesting
all workers should aim to get nominal wage rises that match the level
of inflation is unrealistic, as most will not. Attempts to do so will
just risk recreating what happened after the 1970s: very high
interest rates and a recession. Equally now is not the time for firms
to attempt to generate large increases in profits, because this too
invites a reaction from central banks. But the first is not a
cure for the second, except insofar as a recession hits profits as
well as workers. [1] (As the postscript to this post points out,
larger than average real wage cuts imposed by governments on public
sector workers are a completely different issue.)

For some on the
left, this refocuses the debate on technocratic and undemocratic
independent central banks. After all, if it wasn’t for higher
interest rates, we wouldn’t get a recession. Tooze writes:
“Independent central banks were not truly above politics; they were
the extension of conservative politics by technocratic and non
democratic means.” But, for better or worse, independent central
banks have a mandate to keep inflation near a target. If central
banks were not independent, it is very likely that politicians of all
stripes would set themselves similar inflation targets, and go about
achieving those targets in similar (although probably more erratic) ways.

Some of the dislike
on the left for independent central banks is because the cure to
excess inflation often involves an increase in the number of people
losing their jobs. But this has little to do with central banks per
se, and represents a more general dislike of using demand management to
control inflation, whether it’s through interest rates via an
independent central bank or a government using fiscal or interest
rate policy. The 1970s in the UK in particular represented a
prolonged experiment in attempting to control inflation without
imposing the costs of higher unemployment, and instead using a
mixture of wage and price controls and deals between governments and
trade unions. The result of this experiment was clear – it failed.

There is a more
nuanced criticism of independent central banks with low inflation
targets, which is that they replace the inflationary bias of the
1970s with a deflationary bias. This is the line Tooze takes,
although I think it needs pinning down more precisely than he does in
the article. We have no clear evidence of deflationary bias in the
1990s or early 2000s. In the UK, for example, underlying growth was steady at similar levels to the 1950s, 60s, 70s and 80s.
There is no reason why, in normal times, controlling inflation should
be deflationary, and no good evidence that it generally is.

However it may well
be the case that central banks, given the history of the 1970s,
overreact to similar external shocks to those that happened then.
David Blanchflower has rightly argued
that the Bank of England was too focused on raising rates following
higher commodity prices in the second half of the 2000s to notice the
impact the Global Financial Crisis was having. The ECB raised rates
in 2011 when commodity prices started rising after crashing during
the GFC, and the Bank of England nearly did
the same
. Some might argue that central banks are
overreacting now because the dangers of a wage-price spiral are much
less than in the 1970s.

However it’s far
from clear to me that this shows some flaw in the idea of independent
central banks. Politicians, like independent central banks, are just
as prone to refight the last war. There are ways of dealing with this
deflationary bias without returning to high and variable inflation,
like raising the inflation target or changing
the target in other ways
. Independent central banks with
inflation targets represented a positive response to the inflation of
the 1970s, and there is no reason why these cannot be improved if it
turns out that central banks are overreacting to inflation today. [2]

I noted earlier that
one reason why the left wants to question the image of the 1970s
pushed by the right is because the 1980s saw the beginning of the
neoliberal hegemony. In particular, it saw the start of a decline in
trade unionism in both the UK and US. In addition, and whether it was
a factor behind decline is not obvious, these neoliberal governments
substantially reduced trade union power.

But if it is the
case that we are less likely to get a wage-price spiral leading to a
severe recession today because unions are less powerful, isn’t that
a good thing? There’s an apparent dilemma here which many on the
left are reluctant to face. The dilemma is that there is an inherent
power imbalance between employee and employer in most workplaces and trade unions are important in redressing that imbalance. But is
it possible to have strong unions without also generating wage price
spirals following commodity price hikes?

International
experience suggests the answer may be yes. While trade union density
has declined in many countries in a similar fashion to the US and UK,
in others it has not.

Will these countries
suffer a worse wage price spiral, and therefore recession, than
elsewhere because of greater union coverage? If not, then the link
between widespread unionisation and the high inflation of the 1970s
is less clear cut than many on the right (and some econmists) like to
suggest. There is no dilemma if it is possible to have strong unions
that also recognise when real wages have to fall following higher
commodity prices.

[1] This is why
central bankers who extol wage restraint without also pushing profit
restraint should know better. In the current context both are
inflationary, and the only cure central bankers have for either is
the same: higher interest rates and a decline in economic activity.
There may also be more medium term concerns about rising mark-ups
that are possible because of monopoly or monopsony power in
particular sectors, but there are plenty of medium term remedies
available to governments to deal with those, like encouraging
competition (in the UK’s case, reversing Brexit), better regulation
and a stronger antitrust policy.

[2] There is a
stronger case against separating monetary and fiscal policy, which is
that it facilitates austerity. I make that case here,
although as I argue here
even that strong case ultimately fails.

RELATED ARTICLES

LEAVE A REPLY

Please enter your comment!
Please enter your name here

- Advertisment -
Google search engine

Most Popular

Recent Comments